Consider a preferential system where 11 voters express their preferences as:
5 voters prefer A then B then C
4 voters prefer B then C then A
2 voters prefer C then A then B
With the Borda count A would get 23 points, B would get 24 points, and C would get 19 points, so B would be elected. In instant-runoff, C would be eliminated in the first round and A would be elected in the second round by 7 votes to 4. Now reversing the preferences:
5 voters prefer C then B then A
4 voters prefer A then C then B
2 voters prefer B then A then C
With the Borda count A would get 21 points, B would get 20 points, and C would get 25 points, so this time C would be elected. In instant-runoff, B would be eliminated in the first round and A would as before be elected in the second round, this time by 6 votes to 5.
This example shows that Majority Judgment violates the Reversal symmetry criterion. Assume two candidates A and B and 2 voters with the following ratings:
Candidates/
of voters
A
B
1
Good
Fair
1
Poor
Fair
Now, the winners are determined for the normal and the reversed ballots.
Normal order
In the following the Majority Judgment winner for the normal ballots is determined.
Candidates/
of voters
A
B
1
Good
Fair
1
Poor
Fair
The sorted ratings would be as follows: Result: The median of A is between "Good" and "Poor" and thus is rounded down to "Poor". The median of B is "Fair". Thus, B is elected Majority Judgment winner.
In the following the Majority Judgment winner for the reversed ballots is determined. For reversing, the higher ratings are considered to be mirror-inverted to the lower ratings.
Candidates/
of voters
A
B
1
Poor
Fair
1
Good
Fair
The sorted ratings would be as follows: Result: Still, the median of A is between "Good" and "Poor" and thus is rounded down to "Poor". The median of B is "Fair". Thus, B is elected Majority Judgment winner for the reversed ballots.
Conclusion
B is the Majority Judgment winner using the normal ballots and also using the ballots with reversed ratings. Thus, Majority Judgment fails the Reversal symmetry criterion. However, note that using another rounding method could prevent the failure to Reversal symmetry. Also, note that this situation is unlikely to arise in practical elections with many voters because it involves a "tie" of sorts - some candidate gets exactly the same number of votes above and below a certain value.
Minimax
This example shows that the Minimax method violates the Reversal symmetry criterion. Assume four candidates A, B, C and D with 14 voters with the following preferences:
# of voters
Preferences
4
A > B > D > C
4
B > C > A > D
2
C > D > A > B
1
D > A > B > C
1
D > B > C > A
2
D > C > A > B
Since all preferences are strict rankings, all three Minimax methods elect the same winners. Now, the winners are determined for the normal and the reversed order.
Normal order
In the following the Minimax winner for the ballots in normal order is determined.
# of voters
Preferences
4
A > B > D > C
4
B > C > A > D
2
C > D > A > B
1
D > A > B > C
1
D > B > C > A
2
D > C > A > B
The results would be tabulated as follows:
indicates voters who preferred the candidate listed in the column caption to the candidate listed in the row caption
indicates voters who preferred the candidate listed in the row caption to the candidate listed in the column caption
Result: The candidates A, B, and C form a cycle with clear defeats. D benefits from that since its two losses are relatively close and therefore D's biggest defeat is the closest of all candidates. Thus, D is elected Minimax winner.
Reversed order
In the following the Minimax winner for the ballots in reversed order is determined.
# of voters
Preferences
4
C > D > B > A
4
D > A > C > B
2
B > A > D > C
1
C > B > A > D
1
A > C > B > D
2
B > A > C > D
The results would be tabulated as follows: Result: Still, the candidates A, B, and C form a cycle with clear defeats and D benefits from that. Therefore D's biggest defeat is the closest of all candidates. Thus, D is elected Minimax winner.
Conclusion
D is the Minimax winner using the normal preference order and also using the ballots with reversed preference orders. Thus, Minimax fails the Reversal symmetry criterion.
This example shows that Plurality voting violates the Reversal symmetry criterion. Assume three candidates A, B and C and 4 voters with the following preferences:
# of voters
Preferences
1
A > B > C
1
C > B > A
1
B > A > C
1
C > A > B
Note that reversing all the ballots, leads to the same set of ballots, since the reversed preference order of the first voter resembles the preference order of the second, and similarly with the third and fourth. In the following the Plurality winner is determined. Plurality ballots only contain the single favorite:
# of voters
Favorite
1
A
1
B
2
C
Result: The candidates A and B receive 1 vote each, candidate C receives a plurality of 2 votes. Thus, C is elected Plurality winner. C is the Plurality winner using the normal ballots and also using the reversed ballot. Thus, Plurality fails the Reversal symmetry criterion. Note, that every voting system that satisfies the Reversal symmetry criterion, would have to lead to a tie in this example.