Returns to scale


In economics, returns to scale describe what happens to long run returns as the scale of production increases, when all input levels including physical capital usage are variable. The concept of returns to scale arises in the context of a firm's production function. It explains the long run linkage of the rate of increase in output relative to associated increases in the inputs. In the long run, all factors of production are variable and subject to change in response to a given increase in production scale. While economies of scale show the effect of an increased output level on unit costs, returns to scale focus only on the relation between input and output quantities.
There are three possible types of returns to scale: increasing returns to scale, constant returns to scale, and diminishing returns to scale.
If output increases by the same proportional change as all inputs change then there are constant returns to scale. If output increases by less than that proportional change in all inputs, there are decreasing returns to scale. If output increases by more than the proportional change in all inputs, there are increasing returns to scale. A firm's production function could exhibit different types of returns to scale in different ranges of output. Typically, there could be increasing returns at relatively low output levels, decreasing returns at relatively high output levels, and constant returns at some range of output levels between those extremes.
In mainstream microeconomics, the returns to scale faced by a firm are purely technologically imposed and are not influenced by economic decisions or by market conditions.

Example

When the usages of all inputs increase by a factor of 2, new values for output will be:
Assuming that the factor costs are constant and the production function is homothetic, a firm experiencing constant returns will have constant long-run average costs, a firm experiencing decreasing returns will have increasing long-run average costs, and a firm experiencing increasing returns will have decreasing long-run average costs. However, this relationship breaks down if the firm does not face perfectly competitive factor markets. For example, if there are increasing returns to scale in some range of output levels, but the firm is so big in one or more input markets that increasing its purchases of an input drives up the input's per-unit cost, then the firm could have diseconomies of scale in that range of output levels. Conversely, if the firm is able to get bulk discounts of an input, then it could have economies of scale in some range of output levels even if it has decreasing returns in production in that output range.

Formal definitions

Formally, a production function is defined to have:
where K and L are factors of production—capital and labor, respectively.
In a more general set-up, for a multi-input-multi-output production processes, one may assume technology can be represented via some technology set, call it, which must satisfy some regularity conditions of production theory. In this case, the property of constant returns to scale is equivalent to saying that technology set is a cone, i.e., satisfies the property. In turn, if there is a production function that will describe the technology set it will have to be homogeneous of degree 1.

Formal example

The Cobb–Douglas functional form has constant returns to scale when the sum of the exponents is 1.
In that case the function is:
where and. Thus
Here as input usages all scale by the multiplicative factor a, output also scales by a and so there are constant returns to scale.
But if the Cobb–Douglas production function has its general form
with and then there are increasing returns if b + c > 1 but decreasing returns if b + c < 1, since
which for a > 1 is greater than or less than as b+c is greater or less than one.