Merton's portfolio problem is a well known problem in continuous-time finance and in particular intertemporal portfolio choice. An investor must choose how much to consume and must allocate his wealth between stocks and a risk-free asset so as to maximize expected utility. The problem was formulated and solved by Robert C. Merton in 1969 both for finite lifetimes and for the infinite case. Research has continued to extend and generalize the model to include factors like transaction costs and bankruptcy.
Problem statement
The investor lives from time 0 to time T; his wealth at time t is denoted Wt. He starts with a known initial wealth W0. At time t he must choose what amount of his wealth to consume, ct, and what fraction of wealth to invest in a stock portfolio, πt. The objective is where E is the expectation operator, u is a known utility function, ε parameterizes the desired level of bequest, and ρ is the subjective discount rate. The wealth evolves according to the stochastic differential equation where r is the risk-free rate, are the expected return and volatility of the stock market and dBt is the increment of the Wiener process, i.e. the stochastic term of the SDE. The utility function is of the constant relative risk aversion form: where is a constant which expresses the investor's risk aversion: the higher the gamma, the more reluctance to own stocks. Consumption cannot be negative: ct ≥ 0, while πt is unrestricted. Investment opportunities are assumed constant, that is r, μ, σ are known and constant, in this version of the model, although Merton allowed them to change in his intertemporal CAPM.
Solution
Somewhat surprisingly for an optimal control problem, a closed-form solution exists. The optimal consumption and stock allocation depend on wealth and time as follows: . where and The variable is the subjective utility discount rate.)
Extensions
Many variations of the problem have been explored, but most do not lead to a simple closed-form solution.
Transaction costs can be introduced. For proportional transaction costs the problem was solved by Davis and Norman in 1990. It is one of the few cases of stochastic singular control where the solution is known. For a graphical representation, the amount invested in each of the two assets can be plotted on the x- and y-axes; three diagonal lines through the origin can be drawn: the upper boundary, the Merton line and the lower boundary. The Merton line represents portfolios having the stock/bond proportion derived by Merton in the absence of transaction costs. As long as the point which represents the current portfolio is near the Merton line, i.e. between the upper and the lower boundary, no action needs to be taken. When the portfolio crosses above the upper or below the lower boundary, one should rebalance the portfolio to bring it back to that boundary. In 1994 Shreve and Soner provided an analysis of the problem via the Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation and its viscosity solutions.
The assumption of constant investment opportunities can be relaxed. This requires a model for how change over time. An interest rate model could be added and would lead to a portfolio containing bonds of different maturities. Some authors have added a stochastic volatility model of stock market returns.
Bankruptcy can be incorporated. This problem was solved by Karatzas, Lehoczky, Sethi and Shreve in 1986. Many models incorporating bankruptcy are collected in Sethi.